Xintang, the Blue Jeans City. A worker supervises a power loom weaving denim to be used to manufacture blue jeans in LSH textile company, in Xintang, Guangdong province, China, on February 9, 2012. Photo by Lucas Schifres/Pictobank. Public Domain.
Xintang, the Blue Jeans City. A worker supervises a power loom weaving denim to be used to manufacture blue jeans in LSH textile company, in Xintang, Guangdong province, China, on February 9, 2012. Photo by Lucas Schifres/Pictobank. Public Domain. Source: Flickr.com.
4 min read

Om artiklen

Torkil Lauesen has been an anti-imperialist activist and writer since the late 1960s. His publications in English include “It’s All About Politics,” as well as an interview with him—both of which can be found in Turning Money into Rebellion, edited by Gabriel Kuhn (PM Press, 2014). Zak Cope is the author of Divided World Divided Class: Global Political Economy and the Stratification of Labour under Capitalism (Montréal, Canada: Kersplebedeb, 2012 and 2015) and co-editor, with Immanuel Ness, of the Palgrave Encyclopedia of Imperialism and Anti-Imperialism (Palgrave Macmillan, forthcoming in fall 2015).

The article can be found in other languages:

Chinese: Red ChinaCn.net

DutchImperialisme en de transformatie van waarden in prijzen. (Nieuwe Communistische Partij van Nederland – NCPN) 

Farsi: Rahe Kargar. Organization of Revolutionary workers of Iran

Koreanblog.daum.net/chanhopark

Tyrkisk: Gezite (Shortened translated)

Debate:

An International Working Class? By Rick Patelunas. (DSA Democratic Socialists of America, October 16, 2015)

A fonds perdus La face cachée de l’iPad. Par Ammar Belhimer. (Le Soir d’Algerie, 1er septembre 2015)  

Introduction

In this article, we aim to demonstrate that the low prices of goods produced in the global South and the attendant modest contribution of its exports to the Gross Domestic Product of the North conceals the real dependence of the latter’s economies on low-waged Southern labor. We argue that the relocation of industry to the global South in the past three decades has resulted in a massive increase of transferred value to the North. The principal mechanisms for this transfer are the repatriation of surplus value by means of foreign direct investment, the unequal exchange of products embodying different quantities of value, and extortion through debt servicing.

The incorporation of huge Southern economies into a capitalist world system dominated by global North-based transnational corporations and financial institutions has established the former as socially disarticulated export dependencies. The miserably low wage rates within these economies is predicated upon (1) the pressure imposed by their exports having to compete for limited shares of the largely metropolitan consumer market; (2) the drain of value and natural resources that might otherwise be used to build up the productive forces of the national economy; (3) the unresolved land question creating an oversupply of labor; (4) repressive comprador governments, who benefit from and accept the neoliberal order and are therefore unable and unwilling to grant wage rises for fear of spurring workers’ demands for greater political power; and (5) militarized borders preventing the movement of workers to the global North and, hence, an equalization of returns to labor.

The Imperialist Globalization of Production

The debate on value transfer and unequal exchange is not new. Today, however, an increasingly large proportion of the goods the world consumes are produced in the global South. Production is not, as in the 1970s, limited to primary and simple industrial goods like oil, minerals, coffee, and toys. Rather, despite relatively low manufacturing “value added” (of which more below), virtually all types of industrial inputs and outputs are produced in the global South: these include chemicals, fabricated metal goods, machinery and electrical machinery, electronics, furniture and transport equipment to textiles, shoes, clothes, tobacco, and fuels.1 But why, and how, has this shift in the location of production happened?

The change in the international division of labor is a product of capitals’ perennial quest for higher profits and is based, first, on enormous growth in the number of proletarians integrated into the capitalist world system and, second, on the substantive industrialization of the South over the past three decades. This was made possible by the dissolution of the Soviet and Eastern European “actually existing socialist” economies, the opening of China to global capitalism, and the outsourcing of production to India, Indonesia, Vietnam, Brazil, Mexico, and other newly industrializing countries. The result was an increase of at least one billion low-wage proletarians within global capitalism. Today over 80 percent of the industrial workers in the world are located in the global South, while the proportion falls steadily in the North (see Chart 1). We may be living in post-industrial societies in the North, but the world as a whole is more industrial than ever.